Skip to content
BY 4.0 license Open Access Published by De Gruyter August 25, 2020

Sometimes Your Best Just Ain’t Good Enough: The Worldwide Evidence on Subjective Well-being Efficiency

  • Milena Nikolova EMAIL logo and Olga Popova

Abstract

Most of the studies on subjective well-being focus on the determinants of absolute life satisfaction or happiness levels. This paper asks an important but understudied question, namely, could countries achieve the same or even higher subjective well-being by using the same resources more efficiently? We provide the first country panel evidence on whether nations efficiently transform their endowments (income, education, and health) into subjective well-being and which factors influence the conversion efficiency. Using data on 91 countries from 2009 to 2014, we find that that well-being efficiency gains are possible worldwide. We show that poor labor market conditions as proxied by unemployment and involuntary part-time employment are associated with lower ‘subjective well-being efficiency,’ while social support, freedom, and the rule of law improve it. These findings are useful to policymakers in helping identify inefficiencies, reducing wasteful resource use, and developing policies that promote sustainable development and human well-being. Our results are robust to a battery of sensitivity checks and raise policy-relevant questions about the appropriate instruments to improve subjective well-being efficiency.

JEL codes: I31; D60; O15; P52

1 Introduction

Subjective well-being measures – comprising assessments of positive and negative emotions, life evaluations, and life purpose – have gained popularity in assessing the non-monetary consequences of different behaviors and events.[1] Most papers in the so-called Economics of Happiness literature ask the question: what factors enhance or diminish subjective well-being? In our paper, we ask an important but understudied question, namely, could countries achieve the same or even higher subjective well-being by using the same resources more efficiently? While the determinants of absolute subjective well-being levels are well documented (MacKerron 2012), much less is known about how individuals and countries use their resources and endowments to reach given subjective well-being levels.

Coined by Binder and Broekel (2012a), the term ‘happiness efficiency’ or ‘subjective well-being efficiency’ refers to the efficiency with which individuals or countries convert resources such as income into subjective well-being.[2] The central question of such analyses is how wastefully or productively nations and persons utilize their available resources to reach certain subjective well-being levels, relative to peers with similar or lower resources. In this framework, the most efficient countries and individuals are positioned on a frontier and serve as benchmarks. This benchmark shows the highest achievable subjective well-being, given current resources. Subjective well-being efficiency scores are thus the distance to the country or individual with similar resources and achieving similar absolute subjective well-being levels.[3] More importantly, they also reveal whether there is any waste in the current use of resources, which is a first step towards understanding how it can be minimized.

Subjective well-being efficiency is, therefore, a relative rather than an absolute measure. It is useful for policymakers and society because it demonstrates whether countries could achieve their current levels of subjective well-being with fewer resources (Binder and Broekel 2012a). More importantly, relative subjective well-being analyses reveal why inefficiencies exist and under what conditions these inefficiencies can be reduced. The real value of subjective well-being efficiency analyses for policymakers is in understanding whether and how factors, such as institutions, social norms, and the general socio-demographic composition of the country, help or hinder the conversion of resources into subjective well-being. Such knowledge can help design policies that seek to reduce inefficiencies and empower people to derive satisfaction and meaning from their lives.

Even efficient countries can benefit from such relative subjective well-being analysis. Specifically, they can use subjective well-being efficiency to monitor and identify inefficiencies over time, or understand whether there are inequalities and disparities within particular regions of the country. As such, subjective well-being efficiency analysis can be an additional welfare indicator. Even if enough countries have reached efficiency, the real contribution of the relative subjective well-being measures is decreasing inefficiencies and understanding why they exist.

Thus, by focusing on revealing inefficiencies, relative subjective well-being analyses can be an important complement to standard measures of human progress and absolute subjective well-being. Using a country’s endowments more efficiently and freeing up resources and achieving flourishing with less has implications for sustainability, which has become a key policy priority in recent years. For example, the adoption of the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) and the Paris Agreement have highlighted the importance of developing and embracing approaches to well-being that do not harm the environment but rather preserve it for future generations (Patrick et al. 2019).

A measure of relative subjective well-being also contributes to debates in ecological economics, according to which achieving well-being and progress cannot hinge on continued GDP growth (Hickel 2020). While GDP growth is instrumental for satisfying basic consumption needs, it does not necessarily contribute to subjective well-being in the long-run (Easterlin 2017). Therefore, by utilizing resources more efficiently or equitably, well-being can be achieved without excessive use of resources and endangering the planet’s carrying capacity. This sort of policy-based approach to sustainability and resource use is, in fact, at the heart of the Happy Planet Index, which relates the inequality-adjusted happy life years to the resources it takes to achieve these (Pillarisetti and van den Bergh 2013). The growing consensus that human well-being, poverty reduction, and development must go hand-in-hand with preserving the health of the environment and embracing sustainability (Patrick et al. 2019) will likely make analyses such as those advocated in this paper critical inputs in public policy decision-making in the future.

Our paper both confirms extant findings from Binder and Broekel (2012a) and Cordero, Salinas-Jiménez, and Salinas-Jiménez (2017) and offers novel insights. We substantively contribute to the emergent scholarship on subjective well-being efficiency by applying the approach by Binder and Broekel (2012a) to a balanced country panel setting. Using a robust nonparametric order-α approach (Aragon, Daouia, and Thomas-Agnan 2005), we are the first to utilize a 91-country panel to examine whether these nations optimally reach their subjective well-being levels given their current resources (i.e., income, education and health). Moreover, in our second stage analysis, we also explore the contextual factors that help or hinder efficiency at the country level. For example, none of the existing studies explain which macroeconomic and institutional conditions matter for happiness efficiency, which is a knowledge gap that we fill. Therefore, our study’s insights have direct policy implications for the policy instruments and investments in social infrastructure that can help reduce inefficiencies and provide a sustainable future path.

Our cross-country analyses reveal that subjective well-being efficiency gains are possible worldwide, meaning that nations in our sample could enjoy higher subjective well-being levels given their incomes, health, and human capital. As proxied by unemployment and involuntary part-time employment, poor labor market conditions hinder the conversion of resources into perceived well-being. At the same time, the rule of law, social support, and freedom perceptions improve it. Our findings are robust to a battery of sensitivity checks and raise policy-relevant questions about the appropriate instruments to happiness efficiency.

We contribute to the policy debate and societal knowledge by providing an understanding of well-being that goes beyond the determinants of absolute subjective well-being levels. Instead, we focus on relative subjective well-being and reveal whether inefficiencies exist and what could be done to reduce them to make better use of societies’ scarce resources. Our research also contributes to the new science of well-being measurement by showing that subjective well-being efficiency analyses can be helpful to policymakers and society even in the case of adaptation to bad equilibria. For example, even if people living in countries with dysfunctional institutions report high life satisfaction due to adaptation, subjective well-being efficiency analyses can reveal these inefficiencies and point out their sources.

2 Subjective Well-being Efficiency

Subjective well-being has separate but related dimensions that have different correlates (Graham, Laffan, and Pinto 2018; Graham 2016; Graham and Nikolova 2015; Nikolova 2019; OECD 2013; Stone and Mackie 2014). First, hedonic well-being relates to positive emotions, such as joy and happiness, and negative feelings, such as sadness, worry, anger, and stress at a point in time. Second, evaluative well-being refers to a reflective assessment of one’s life as a whole. This dimension is typically measured using survey questions on life satisfaction or Cantril’s ladder of life, asking respondents to rate their current life relative to the best possible life that they can imagine on a scale of 0–10 (Cantril 1965). Some scholars consider a third subjective well-being dimension – eudaimonia – which refers to the Aristotelian notion of happiness as challenges, mastery, skills and achievement, meaning and purpose in life, and the capacity to make life choices (Graham 2016).

While the subjective well-being approach has primarily focused on studying the determinants of happiness and life satisfaction, the capability approach has focused ‘conversion efficiency’ (Binder and Broekel 2011, 2012b; Hick 2016; Martinetti 2000). The idea of subjective well-being efficiency closely relates to the conversion efficiency from the capability approach. According to the conversion efficiency framework, individuals translate income and resources into achieved functionings, which are states of being and doing, such as being happy, educated, well-fed, clothed (Binder and Broekel 2012b; Sen 1999). The idea is that people with the same access to resources may differ in their capacity to benefit from these resources. Individual factors, such as health conditions, risk preferences, or personality traits could influence the conversion. External factors, such as country characteristics, the rule of law, regulations, and the environment can also play a role (Binder and Broekel 2011). As Binder and Broekel (2011) note, information about conversion efficiency can be useful to policymakers in changing institutional or individual factors, such as disability or unemployment. Yet, both relative subjective well-being and conversion efficiency have received relatively little attention in the literature.

To date, three papers have explored happiness efficiency at either the individual (Binder and Broekel 2012a; Cordero, Salinas-Jiménez, and Salinas-Jiménez 2017) or country level (Debnath and Shankar 2014). First, Binder and Broekel (2012a, 2012b) use individual-level panel data from the British Household Panel study and find that 20–27% of the population efficiently reaches its life satisfaction levels. In their second-stage fixed effects regression, the authors document that unemployment reduces efficiency, while marriage and cohabitation increase it. Finally, retirement is efficiency-enhancing among males, while maternity leave has the same influence on females.

Second, Cordero, Salinas-Jiménez, and Salinas-Jiménez (2017) use cross-sectional data on individuals from 26 nations from the 2005–6 World Values Survey and include individual- and country-level variables, discovering that the most efficient countries are also those with the highest absolute life satisfaction levels (for example, Netherlands, Sweden, Finland, New Zealand), while Russia, South Korea, China, and Indonesia are among the least efficient. In regressions using efficiency scores as the dependent variable, the authors also document that women, the religious, the married, and those who are not unemployed are efficient in reaching their subjective well-being levels. The results regarding having children are less clear-cut, and age is conducive to happiness efficiency but turns negative after age 85. Adding country-level variables reveals that health, education expenditures, and institutional quality improve efficiency, while the unemployment rate and gender inequality reduce it. GDP per capita is not significant in these efficiency regressions, meanwhile. A major drawback of the Cordero, Salinas-Jiménez, and Salinas-Jiménez (2017) study is its cross-sectional nature and the lack of cross-country variation.

Finally, Debnath and Shankar (2014) investigate the efficiency of good governance policies in 130 countries using the cross-sectional data from the World Database of Happiness. They calculate the efficiency index as a weighted sum of outputs (average happiness and happiness inequality) divided by the weighted sum of inputs (various indicators of good governance). The authors reach the surprising conclusion that most developed countries are rather inefficient in increasing the population’s happiness using ‘good governance’ policies, while some developing nations are surprisingly efficient (for example, Nepal). The authors do not go beyond the calculation and classification of the efficiency scores and do not explore which factors help or hinder efficiency.

We extend the nascent happiness efficiency literature in several ways. First, we provide the first subjective well-being efficiency insights from a country-level panel comprising nations at different levels of development. The panel structure ensures that countries are compared to the same set of peers year after year. Second, in the second-stage regressions, we also explore the factors enhancing or reducing efficiency. Third, we also provide guidance on how analyses of relative subjective well-being can inform policy debates related to sustainability.

In this paper, we focus on output-oriented efficiency, which relates to how much additional output (if any) could be produced with current resources.[4] Countries are compared to a peer nation or a sample of nations with a similar or lower level of resources that achieve similar subjective well-being levels. More formally, countries are compared to peers at a particular percentile of the SWB distribution, as explained in the next section. Given our balanced panel structure, nations are compared to the same set of potential peers over time, which is an advantage of our paper over Cordero, Salinas-Jiménez, and Salinas-Jiménez (2017) and Debnath and Shankar (2014).

Revealed inefficiencies could be due to a variety of factors, such as institutional hindrances or a lack of information about how to utilize resources productively. In this paper, we provide evidence about which institutional or macroeconomic variables help to reduce inefficiencies. These insights can be directly translated into policy advice, by, for example, revealing that institutional reforms improve not only absolute levels of well-being but also help achieve this well-being more sustainably and efficiently. We detail our methodology in the next section.

3 Methods

Following Binder and Broekel (2012a), our analytical strategy comprises two steps: first, we use the input (i.e., income, education and health) and output (i.e., subjective well-being) variables to estimate efficiency scores using nonparametric robust frontier analysis (Daraio and Simar 2007); and second, using the efficiency scores as the dependent variables, we conduct country-fixed effects regressions to offer insights into which background characteristics increase or reduce efficiency. We detail the choice of inputs and background characteristics in section 3.3.

The fact that we have a country panel offers several advantages compared to cross-sectional studies, such as Cordero, Salinas-Jiménez, and Salinas-Jiménez (2017) and Debnath and Shankar (2014). Specifically, given our longitudinal data, in the first stage, we compare countries to a fixed set of potential peers, minimizing the possibility that changes in the analysis sample composition drive changes in efficiency scores from year to year. Second, the country-fixed effect estimations in the second stage allow us to mitigate sources of endogeneity related to time-invariant heterogeneity. These include culture and norms when discerning the role of different factors for determining efficiency. As the empirical strategy is identical at the individual- and country- levels, we only detail the specifications at the country level.

3.1 First Stage

We rely on the order-α method (Aragon, Daouia, and Thomas-Agnan 2005) based on the conditional quantiles of the appropriate distribution of the production process. In the output-oriented case, the efficiency score reflects the maximum possible increase in subjective well-being that could be achieved if current resources are used efficiently. In the simplest scenario, we assume that for each country i = 1,…, N, we have one input xi and one output yi. We compare country i to a set of countries Bi that have similar or lower levels of input(s) (xj ≤ xi) and achieve subjective well-being levels at the 100 percentile P of the subjective well-being distribution (α ranges from 0 to 1). Thus, 100*(1—α)% demonstrates the probability that country i is dominated by those countries in the peer set with a similar or lower level of resources.

The efficiency score is defined as:

(1)θ^i=pαjBimin{yjyi}

Efficiency scores greater than one indicate inefficiency. Values equal to one indicate efficiency and values less than one indicate super efficiency (i.e., countries achieving higher well-being than expected given current resources). Importantly, super efficiency is possible as the robust nonparametric methods do not envelope all data points, making the method less sensitive to outliers. Efficiency scores greater (smaller) than one show the possible proportionate increase (decrease) in subjective well-being given current resources. In other words, the efficiency score gives the proportionate increase or decrease in outputs needed to move the given country to the order-α output frontier, whereby it is dominated by countries using similar or fewer inputs with a probability (1—α) (Daraio and Simar 2007).

The value of α can be seen as a tuning parameter that determines how many observations would not be enveloped and would be considered ‘super-efficient.’ In the main analyses, we set α to 0.95 and rely on bootstrapped standard errors with 500 replications but also offer specifications with different α values in Tables B3–B6 in Online Appendix B.

We also provide robustness checks with the order-m approach (Cazals, Florens, and Simar 2002) (see Tables B15–B16 in Online Appendix B). Despite some similarities, the order-m and order-α approaches differ from each other. In the order-m approach, countries or individuals are benchmarked with the expected best performance among m peers (Tauchmann 2012). In a re-sampling, which occurs D times, the units are compared to a randomly drawn sample of m peers. This method is time-consuming, and choosing the appropriate m value is done by trial and error. Rather than the minimum input consumption among m peers as the benchmark, the order-α relies on the 100*(1—α)th percentile, as explained above (Tauchmann 2012). It is also our preferred approach because it is less computationally intensive and easily implemented via Stata’s routine orderalpha (Tauchmann 2012).

3.2 Second Stage

In the second stage, we examine the determinants of efficiency scores using country-fixed effects regressions. Specifically, we estimate the following:

(2)Ect=α+B'ctβ+πc+τt+uct

whereby E is the efficiency score estimated in step one, B is a vector of background variables (the rule of law, generosity, social support, and employment status), π and τ are country and year fixed effects, respectively, and u is the stochastic error term. All regressions thus rely on within-country variation and include robust standard errors clustered at the country level. The time fixed effects ensure that our second-stage regressions mitigate endogeneity issues related to common shocks (such as economic crises or business cycles) as well as certain time-invariant characteristics at the country level, such as social norms, culture, geography, and others via the country fixed effects.[5] For comparison purposes and to understand the role of time-invariant heterogeneity, we also provide specifications without country fixed effects in Table C1 in Online Appendix C.

3.3 Inputs and Background Characteristics

The choice of inputs and background variables when implementing two-stage efficiency analyses is subject to debate (Cordero et al. 2016; Ravallion 2005). While we cannot settle this debate, we motivate the choices of input and background factors based on existing studies in the literature. In addition, Like Binder and Broekel (2012a), we do not define happiness efficiency in a deterministic and all-encompassing way. Rather, we select the key inputs while also allowing for the influence intervening or background factors in the second stage analysis.

Our primary argument for the selection of the resources in the first stage and the environmental factors in the second one is that certain ‘capital’ factors are necessary to create subjective well-being. In contrast, the conversion process of resources into subjective well-being depends on the quality of the social fabric, formal and informal institutions, and labor market conditions. As such, we see the capital variables as inputs and institutions and labor market conditions as background factors.

Specifically, following Binder and Broekel (2012a) and Cordero, Salinas-Jiménez, and Salinas-Jiménez (2017), our inputs feature income, education, and health, which we measure as log real GDP per capita, the share of individuals with secondary educational attainment, and life expectancy.[6] We follow the subjective well-being literature in logging GDP, although in the efficiency literature logging GPD is unnecessary (Binder and Broekel 2012a). In addition, theoretically, income, health, and education are proxies of ‘capital’ –financial, health, and human capital – whereby an increase in these variables is positively associated with subjective well-being (Helliwell, Huang, and Wang 2016). Specifically, in addition to generosity, social support, the rule of law, and freedom, GDP per capita, education, and health explain 75% of the cross-country variation in life evaluations (Helliwell, Huang, and Wang 2016). Furthermore, income, health, and education often feature in indices of development or progress. For example, these three factors comprise the three components of the Human Development Index, which is conceptually based on Sen’s capability approach. As such, it represents the key ingredients (or inputs) of human well-being. Income promotes subjective well-being, at least in the short run (Easterlin 2017), and health and education are basic capabilities enabling quality of life. Importantly, as Anand and Sen (2000) point out, while income may be correlated with health and education, control over resources does not necessarily result in good healthcare and education.[7] As expected, the correlation coefficients between some of these input variables are moderate to high. For example, the correlation coefficient between income and life expectancy is 0.8, and that between income and education is 0.6. Income and education are also correlated (ρ = 0.5). Nevertheless, each of these variables has its contribution to life evaluations above and beyond the other ones, as shown in Table C2.

Conceptually, background characteristics should capture the environmental variables affecting the conversion of inputs to subjective well-being and reflect institutions and the quality of the social fabric. We thus rely on the variables from Helliwell, Huang, and Wang ’s (2016) list of factors explaining three-quarters of the cross-country variation in life evaluation scores and have included additional employment controls, which capture the state of the labor markets. Specifically, we use the rule of law, generosity, freedom, social support, as well as country-level employment status variables. The rule of law reflects contract enforcement, property rights, and the functioning of the legal system and, as such, is a measure of legal institutions (Berggren and Bjørnskov 2020). Like others in the literature (Adsera, Boix, and Payne 2003; Nikolova 2016), we argue that measures, such as good governance, control of corruption, and government stability are consequences of good institutions and not institutions themselves.

Generosity and social support capture the quality of the social interactions, or social capital, while the employment status controls reflect the functioning of the labor markets. In Online Appendix B, we provide a battery of sensitivity checks with different input, output, and background variables, which suggest that our results are not sensitive to the choice of the input and background variables or their measurement.

3.4 Empirical Considerations

Efficiency analyses and the cross-country panel regressions assume comparability of subjective well-being scores across countries. Specifically, if the differences in subjective well-being scores among countries are due to noise, measurement error, and cultural differences in reporting styles, international comparisons of subjective well-being are arguably uninformative. Nonetheless, the literature shows that only a small component of subjective well-being is due to noise. As noted above, Helliwell, Huang, and Wang (2016) show that up to one-fifth of the variation in cross-country life evaluation scores is attributable to unobservables, measurement error, and cultural bias. Exton, Smith, and Vandendriessche (2015) show that the plausible magnitude of cultural bias in life evaluations is between 0.19 and 0.61 (on a scale of 0–10), comprising between 5.6 and 18% of the country-level unexplained variance, suggesting that country-level subjective well-being differences are meaningful.

Furthermore, efficiency analysis compares countries and individuals to a benchmark comprising the best-performing peers, that is, units with the same or lower level of resources achieving the same or higher subjective well-being levels. Therefore, defining and empirically estimating the benchmark is an important practical issue. Binder and Broekel (2011) and Ravallion (2005) summarize the different empirical approaches to determining the frontiers. Parametric methods rely on the specification of a single production frontier, which describes the process of translating the inputs into maximum possible output. Econometric techniques are used to fit the frontier’s parameters, whereby it fully envelops the data, and no observations are left outside of it. In other words, for a given input level, no production unit (i.e., country) achieves more output than predicted by the function. The distance between the predicted and actual output is a measure of inefficiency. While this is the most common application of production theory in the literature, we share Ravallion’s (2005) and Binder and Broekel’s (2011, 2012a) criticism of parametric approaches, namely that the specification of a functional form is problematic. Importantly, misspecification of the functional form can lead to errors, including wrongly classifying countries as inefficient (Ravallion 2005). As the exact process of converting resources into subjective well-being is unknown, picking one functional form over another and assuming that all countries utilize the same production technology is problematic (Binder and Broekel 2011).

Binder and Broekel (2012a) offer a second criticism of the parametric approach, claiming that while the inputs, such as income, education, and health, influence conversion efficiency, they may also affect the conversion of other inputs into subjective well-being. This criticism relates to the interdependency of inputs; for example, individuals or countries use income as an input in the perceived well-being production process. However, income itself may also influence how other resources are translated into subjective well-being. A similar logic applies to health and education. Accordingly, it is difficult to model the complex relationships among the inputs and between each input and the output. Nonetheless, parametric approaches require modeling of the dependencies and, as such, are particularly problematic (Binder and Broekel 2012a). In summary, parametric methods only allow single production technology and require the specification of the functional form, modeling the endogeneity among the inputs, and assumptions regarding the error term (Tauchmann 2012).

Nonparametric techniques such as the Free Disposal Hull (FDH) and DEA address some of the critiques outlined above. As they are fitted by mathematical optimization processes, nonparametric methods do not require a parametric model specification. Nonetheless, the DEA – which is used in Debnath and Shankar (2014) – has several shortcomings (Dyson et al. 2001) and is inappropriate in our case because it assumes convexity, meaning that inputs (outputs) can be substituted. In our framework, this would imply that countries could substitute income for health – for example – on the inputs side, or happiness and life evaluations on the output end, which is not defensible. Moreover, the FDH is also inappropriate in our case as it is very sensitive to outliers, given that all variations among the observations are attributed to efficiency rather than a stochastic element.

Robust nonparametric methods or partial frontier approaches, such as the order-m, and order-α (Aragon, Daouia, and Thomas-Agnan 2005; Cazals, Florens, and Simar 2002; Daouia and Simar 2005, 2007; Daraio and Simar 2005) tackle these critiques and as such are our preferred estimation strategy. These approaches are robust to data outliers because not all points are used in creating the frontier, and the production process is probability-based and described by a conditional distribution function (Aragon, Daouia, and Thomas-Agnan 2005; Tauchmann 2012). In other words, these techniques involve a partial rather than a full frontier enveloping all data. The idea is not to estimate the absolute highest technically feasible output for a given level of input, but rather to ‘estimate something close to it’ (Simar and Wilson 2008). The partial frontier approaches also avoid the ‘curse of dimensionality,’ meaning that they do not demand thousands of observations to avoid statistical imprecision (Daraio and Simar 2007). Given that there are only 91 countries in our panel, the curse of dimensionality problem would have been serious with traditional nonparametric estimators.

4 Data, Sample, and Variables

We rely on country-level data from Gallup Analytics (2009–2014), based on the GWP, a yearly survey of about 150 countries worldwide. The GWP data are collected via in-person interviews in developing and transition countries and via landline and cell phone interviews in the OECD countries. For the cross-country regressions, we merge the Gallup data with GDP per capita information from the World Bank, life expectancy data from the United Nations (2015), and in our robustness checks, with years of schooling from the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP). Finally, we use data on the rule of law from the Worldwide Governance Indicators (Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi 2010). As a robustness check, we replace the rule of law with aggregate generalized trust in Table B2 in Online Appendix B.

Our cross-country analyses include macro-level variables for the output, inputs, and background variables (Table 1). Our main output variable is life evaluations, measured on a scale of 0–10 using Cantril’s ladder of life question. Specifically, respondents are asked to imagine a ladder with steps going from 0 (the worst possible life that they can imagine for themselves) to 10 (the best possible life that they can imagine) and to rate their current life on this ladder. The ladder-of-life question is self-anchoring, which means that the scale is relative to each respondent’s aspirations and understanding of his/her best possible life. In the macro-level analyses, we use the country-average value of the individual-level survey responses. In Tables B7 and B8, we show that our conclusions are robust to testing our specifications with financial satisfaction as the output.

Table 1:

Variable definitions.

VariableExplanation
Output variable
Life evaluation (0–10)Country average of responses to ‘Please imagine a ladder, with steps numbered from 0 at the bottom to 10 at the top. The top of the ladder represents the best possible life for you, and the bottom of the ladder represents the worst possible life for you. On which step of the ladder would you say you personally feel you stand at this time?’
Inputs
GDP per capita at 2011 PPP (log scale)Log-transformed GDP per capita at 2011 PPP
Secondary educationShare of Gallup World Poll respondents who completed some secondary education and/or up to three years of tertiary education (i.e., 9–15 years of education)
Life expectancyLife expectancy at birth, both sexes combined (years)
Background
Out of the labor forceShare of Gallup World Poll respondents reporting to be out of the workforce
Involuntary part-timeShare of Gallup World Poll respondents reporting to be employed part-time but wants to be employed full-time
UnemployedShare of Gallup World Poll respondents reporting to be unemployed
Voluntary part-timeShare of Gallup World Poll respondents reporting to be employed part-time and does not want full-time
Full-timeShare of Gallup World Poll respondents reporting to be employed full-time for an employer
Self-employedShare of Gallup World Poll respondents reporting to be employed full-time for self
Social supportShare of Gallup World Poll respondents reporting ‘yes’ to ‘If you were in trouble, do you have relatives or friends you can count on to help you whenever you need them, or not?’
GenerosityShare of Gallup World Poll respondents reporting ‘yes’ to ‘Have you done any of the following in the past month? How about donated money to a charity?’
Rule of LawCountry-level information based on the Worldwide Governance Indicators, ‘Capturing perceptions of the extent to which agents have confidence in and abide by the rules of society, and in particular the quality of contract enforcement, property rights, the police, and the courts, as well as the likelihood of crime and violence’ (Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi 2010, p. 4)
FreedomShare of Gallup World Poll respondents reporting ‘satisfied’ to ‘Your freedom to choose what you do with your life.’
  1. Sources: Authors based on Gallup Analytics (Gallup Inc 2015). Income data from the World Development Indicators Database, Rule of Law data from the Worldwide Governance Indicators Life expectancy from UNDP (United Nations; Department of Economic and Social Affairs; Population Division, 2015). All variables are measured at the country level.

Since the order-α method is sensitive to the composition of the sample and the number of observations, we created a fully balanced panel with as many country-years as possible. To achieve this goal, we impute some observations by replacing missing values with the simple averages. For completeness, we also note that specifications without the imputations, shown in Tables B17 and B18 in Online Appendix B, are virtually identical to the main results. As Table A1 in Online Appendix A demonstrates, the number of imputed values is low, and the averages and standard deviations are virtually identical for the imputed and non-imputed samples. Our final sample comprises 91 countries at different levels of development (Table A2 in Online Appendix A).

5 Results

5.1 First Stage: Efficiency Scores

Table 2 shows the country-level efficiency scores over the analysis period (2009–2014). The second column features the mean efficiency score for all 91 countries in the sample, which is, on average, about 1.1 over the analysis period. For example, the efficiency score of 1.088 in 2014 suggests that given their resources in 2014, the 91 nations could have achieved life evaluation levels that were, on average, 8.8% higher than was actually the case. In other words, in 2014, the 91 countries had an average absolute life evaluation score of 5.49, whereas if they had they efficiently used their resources, they could have achieved a score of 5.97. Table 2’s fourth column details that about half of the countries in the sample are happiness-inefficient, suggesting that large subjective well-being efficiency gains are possible worldwide. These findings are in line with the findings in Cordero, Salinas-Jiménez, and Salinas-Jiménez (2017), who document an efficiency score of about 1.2–1.7 (depending on the specification) for the individual-level sample based on data from 26 countries for 2005–2006 (and using similar input variables). While the magnitude of the possible subjective well-being gain is instructive, it is most useful as a diagnostic to reveal whether and where inefficiencies exist. The second stage analysis provides complementary policy-relevant information about what could be done to minimize or eliminate such inefficiencies.

Table 2:

Efficiency scores, α = 0.95, a balanced panel of 91 countries, 2009–2014.

YearMean efficiencyMedian efficiencyPct. inefficientMean life eval.Mean life eval. If efficientPossible life eval. Gain
20091.0981.0320.5385.5006.0390.539
20101.0981.0550.5495.5126.0520.540
20111.0811.0370.5505.5125.9590.447
20121.0701.0000.4845.4755.8580.383
20131.0701.0000.4955.4445.8250.381
20141.0881.0470.5825.4895.9720.483
  1. Sources: Authors based on education and life evaluations data from Gallup Analytics; Income data from the World Development Indicators Database, Life expectancy data from the United Nations.

  2. Notes: The efficiency scores are computed based on an order-α procedure using country-level information on income (GDP per capita), education, and health as inputs and life evaluations (best possible life evaluations) as an output. The method, described in detail in Section 3, compares each country i to a set of countries that have similar or lower levels of inputs and achieve subjective well-being levels at the 95th percentile of the subjective well-being distribution. Efficiency scores greater than one indicate inefficiency and show the extent to which a country can increase its subjective well-being with current resources. Efficiency scores equal to one indicate that resources, i.e., income, education, or health are optimally used, and no subjective well-being improvements are possible without changing the inputs.

Furthermore, our results have substantive implications for development economics because they imply that subjective quality of life for the world could be improved without increasing current resources or relying on continuous economic growth. As such, this has important implications for recent debates over sustainability because reducing the inefficiencies in the current use of resources can provide large global gains in terms of human well-being and flourishing.

In Table 3, we detail the efficiency scores for all 91 countries for 2014. This table reveals several important insights. First, we show that low life evaluations do not necessarily translate into low happiness efficiency. For example, Albania, Greece, Tunisia, and South Africa all had life evaluation scores of 4.8 points (on a scale of 0–10) in 2014. Yet, Greece performed the worst among this country set in terms of efficiency, while South Africa performed the best among this group. Such comparisons reveal that relative and absolute subjective well-being measures provide complementary information and help reveal nuances that can be informative to policy. For example, this information could be useful to a policymaker in Greece to raise awareness about the inefficiency in the first place and then examine what could be done to reduce it. Second, even countries that appear to be using their endowments relatively efficiently could benefit from the analyses detailed in Table 3. For example, South African policymakers can compare their relative performance over time, as efficiency scores can and do change. They can also rely on within-country happiness efficiency analysis to better understand if all regions and individuals within these regions benefit equally from resources or whether particular cities or areas or socio-demographic groups require specific policy interventions.[8] Second, high levels of absolute subjective well-being also do not automatically entail happiness efficiency. Improvements in relative happiness are even possible in Denmark, which is often at the top of different world rankings on life evaluations. Therefore, even countries with already high absolute subjective well-being scores can gain knowledge about their relative subjective well-being.

Table 3:

Life evaluations (output), income, education, health (inputs), and subjective well-being efficiency scores, 2014.

CountryLife evaluations (output)Log GDP per capita (2011 PPP) (input 1)Secondary education share (input 2)Life expectancy (input 3)Efficiency scoreStd. error of efficiency scoreZ-stat of efficiency scoreRank 1 = best, 91 = worst, based on efficiency scoreReference for efficiency score calculation
Afghanistan3.17.5200.24060.3621.2900.1342.16186Mali
Albania4.89.2240.32077.7711.2290.0892.56677El Salvador
Armenia4.58.9490.62074.7171.2000.1341.49069Pakistan
Austria6.910.6900.79081.3911.0140.0260.55739Brazil
Azerbaijan5.39.7240.75070.8141.0570.0481.18851Indonesia
Bahrain6.210.6780.57076.5781.0480.0640.75847Guatemala
Bangladesh4.67.9990.47071.6091.0870.0561.55860Nepal
Belarus5.89.7610.65071.3170.9660.0430.8107Indonesia
Bolivia5.98.7520.67068.3481.0000.0720.0009Bolivia
Bosnia and Herz.5.29.1580.49076.4821.2120.0792.67573Nicaragua
Brazil7.09.6230.51074.4721.0000.0770.0009Brazil
Bulgaria4.49.7030.48074.2091.3410.1142.98988El Salvador
Cambodia3.98.0430.09068.3581.0770.0352.19356Niger
Cameroon4.27.9500.40055.5161.0000.0800.0009Cameroon
Canada7.310.6640.59082.0440.9590.0341.2176Brazil
Chad3.57.6410.13051.5811.000..9Chad
Chile6.89.9980.61081.6601.0290.0340.87343Brazil
Colombia6.49.4530.59074.0381.0000.0640.0009Colombia
Costa Rica7.29.5630.39079.4271.0000.1140.0009Costa Rica
Croatia5.49.9050.54077.3191.2960.0604.95487Brazil
Cyprus5.610.2980.50080.1561.2500.0713.50681Thailand
Czech Republic6.510.2650.68078.6061.0150.0310.50041Panama
Denmark7.510.6630.83080.2450.9330.0361.8522Brazil
Dominican Rep.5.49.4460.24073.4701.0000.0780.0009Dominican
Ecuador5.99.2920.70075.8901.0680.0491.38355Nicaragua
Egypt4.99.2150.46071.1321.1020.0571.78361Pakistan
El Salvador5.98.9830.27073.0191.0000.0870.0009El Salvador
France6.510.5240.67082.1621.0460.0321.42445Chile
Georgia4.38.8860.55074.8711.2560.1521.68783Pakistan
Germany7.010.6830.68080.9171.0000.0290.0009Brazil
Ghana3.98.2670.51061.3501.0770.0451.69456Cameroon
Greece4.810.1010.55080.8771.4580.0578.03391Brazil
Guatemala6.58.8690.44071.8281.0000.1110.0009Guatemala
Honduras5.18.4520.37073.1361.0590.0660.89852Pakistan
India4.48.6010.43067.9881.2270.0912.48875Pakistan
Indonesia5.69.2140.49068.8711.0000.0670.0009Indonesia
Iraq4.59.5730.32069.4301.2000.1081.84469Pakistan
Ireland7.010.7880.59080.8701.0000.0270.0009Brazil
Israel7.410.3570.68082.3650.9460.0321.6875Brazil
Italy6.010.4050.40083.1431.1670.0871.92266Thailand
Japan5.910.4810.62083.5321.1530.0374.13263Chile
Jordan5.39.3500.64074.0211.1130.0721.56762El Salvador
Kazakhstan6.010.0480.63069.3780.9330.0541.2332Indonesia
Kenya4.97.9440.42061.6091.0000.0930.0009Kenya
Kyrgyzstan5.38.0610.69070.5691.0000.0480.0009Kyrgyzstan
Lebanon5.29.7210.48079.2741.2880.0823.52885Mexico
Lithuania6.110.1590.50073.3221.0000.0620.0009Lithuania
Macedonia5.29.4160.45075.3791.2120.0792.68973Nicaragua
Malaysia6.010.1050.69074.7381.0830.0631.33259Guatemala
Mali4.07.3300.16058.0031.000..9Mali
Mauritania4.58.2250.32063.0551.0000.0700.0009Mauritania
Mexico6.79.6980.42076.7751.0000.0660.0009Mexico
Moldova5.98.4670.64071.5611.0000.0720.0009Moldova
Montenegro5.39.5840.60076.2451.2080.0732.83472Colombia
Nepal5.07.7250.16069.6151.0000.0980.0009Nepal
Nicaragua6.38.4540.40074.9231.0000.0980.0009Nicaragua
Niger4.26.7960.05061.4281.000..9Niger
Nigeria5.08.6380.55052.7621.0000.1420.0009Nigeria
Pakistan5.48.4320.16066.1711.0000.1250.0009Pakistan
Palestinian Territories4.78.3670.64072.8981.0640.0222.84354Nepal
Panama6.69.9000.55077.5791.0150.0410.36940Mexico
Paraguay5.19.0480.51072.9021.2750.1322.08784Guatemala
Peru5.99.3450.72074.5571.0000.0490.0009Bolivia
Philippines5.38.8020.59068.2001.0190.0460.41042Pakistan
Poland5.810.0850.63077.4251.1550.0453.41264Mexico
Portugal5.110.1730.35080.9271.3730.1422.61690Thailand
Romania5.79.8570.57074.6931.2280.0952.38976Brazil
Russia6.010.0560.60070.0980.9330.0551.2012Indonesia
Saudi Arabia6.310.8100.58074.2991.0000.0530.0009Saudi Arabia
Senegal4.47.7080.25066.4931.0000.0650.0009Senegal
Serbia5.19.4510.50074.8901.1570.0881.78965El Salvador
Slovenia5.710.2450.75080.3861.1750.0453.90667Mexico
South Africa4.89.4290.68057.3911.0470.0880.53146Nigeria
South Korea5.810.4230.46081.8701.2070.0673.06671Thailand
Spain6.510.3670.75082.5791.0770.0362.14558Brazil
Sri Lanka4.39.2750.48074.8841.3720.1252.98589El Salvador
Sweden7.210.6930.70082.1800.9720.0271.0388Brazil
Tajikistan4.97.8510.60069.4251.0000.0680.0009Tajikistan
Tanzania3.57.7920.19064.9681.2000.0702.87268Niger
Thailand7.09.6170.35074.4371.0000.1070.0009Thailand
Tunisia4.89.2970.41074.8331.2290.0782.93777El Salvador
Turkey5.69.8450.59075.2601.2500.0753.32781Brazil
Uganda3.87.4320.38058.5001.0530.0252.14750Mali
Ukraine4.39.0200.64070.9651.2330.0435.35979Philippines
United Kingdom6.810.5500.58080.6941.0290.0320.91743Brazil
United States7.210.8610.66079.0840.9310.0351.9741Mexico
Uruguay6.69.9000.52077.1961.0610.0491.23853Brazil
Venezuela6.19.7260.62074.2071.0490.0570.86848Colombia
Vietnam5.18.5890.52075.7901.2350.1112.12680Nicaragua
Yemen4.08.2710.27063.8381.0500.0580.85849Niger
Zimbabwe4.27.4440.58057.5341.000..9Zimbabwe
  1. Sources: Authors based on education and life evaluations data from Gallup Analytics; Income data from the World Development Indicators Database, Life expectancy data from the United Nations.

  2. Notes: For each country in the analysis sample in the year 2014, the table shows the absolute life evaluation levels (output), the levels of the three inputs (income, education, and health), the calculated efficiency score, standard error and z-statistic associated with the efficiency score, and the reference country. The presented rankings are based on the efficiency scores, i.e., on relative rather than absolute SWB scores. The efficiency scores are computed based on an order-α procedure using country-level information on income, education, and health as inputs and life evaluations (best possible life evaluations) as an output. The method, described in detail in Section 3, compares each country i to a set of countries that have similar or lower levels of inputs and achieve subjective well-being levels at the 95th percentile of the subjective well-being distribution. Efficiency scores greater than one indicate inefficiency and show the extent to which a country can increase its subjective well-being with current resources. Efficiency scores equal to one indicate that resources, such as income, education, or health, are optimally used, and no subjective well-being improvements are possible without changing the inputs. The standard errors are bootstrapped (500 replications). The bootstrapping cannot determine non-zero standard errors (z-statistics) for countries, for which no or very few peers are available in the analysis sample, besides the country itself. For these cases, no standard errors are reported.

Nonetheless, readers should exert caution when interpreting the efficiency scores for very poor developing countries. While these countries often appear efficient, this could be because of a lack of comparison countries with lower levels of resources, meaning that the method automatically picks the country itself as the frontier. To ensure that outliers do not drive our results in the second stage, we report all regressions in Table 4 as well as those in Online Appendix B with and without the worst-endowed countries (see the list of low-income countries in Online Appendix Table A2).

Table 4:

Second stage fixed effects regressions, α = 0.95, 2009–2014.

Full sample of 91 countriesSample without the low-income countries
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
Out of the labor force−0.189−0.082−0.200−0.067
(0.356)(0.093)(0.368)(0.104)
Involuntary part-time−0.331−0.228−0.345−0.212
(0.356)(0.146)(0.380)(0.165)
Unemployed−0.550−0.451***−0.595−0.466***
(0.378)(0.151)(0.384)(0.169)
Voluntary part-time0.0140.284*−0.0600.218
(0.414)(0.164)(0.402)(0.146)
Full-time−0.1670.093−0.1740.100
(0.381)(0.119)(0.400)(0.130)
Self-employed−0.0970.165*−0.1100.172
(0.344)(0.090)(0.346)(0.108)
Social support0.173**0.154*0.151*0.164*0.197**0.1640.163*0.179*
(0.083)(0.084)(0.082)(0.086)(0.097)(0.099)(0.097)(0.100)
Generosity0.0140.0220.0240.0210.0100.0190.0180.017
(0.043)(0.043)(0.042)(0.043)(0.047)(0.048)(0.046)(0.047)
Rule of Law0.091***0.077**0.074**0.086**0.115***0.099***0.097***0.112***
(0.033)(0.032)(0.032)(0.034)(0.038)(0.036)(0.037)(0.039)
Freedom0.120**0.100*0.101*0.104*0.0760.0610.0630.063
(0.059)(0.056)(0.055)(0.057)(0.058)(0.056)(0.054)(0.056)
Constant0.461***0.718**0.614***0.429***0.391***0.678*0.546***0.361**
(0.122)(0.347)(0.134)(0.123)(0.140)(0.355)(0.154)(0.142)
Year FEYYYYYYYY
Country FEYYYYYYYY
Observations546546546546492492492492
Adjusted R20.7250.7310.7320.7280.7440.7480.7500.745
Number of countries9191919182828282
F-stat3.3672.4642.9712.6962.7332.1792.5462.261
  1. Sources: Authors based on Gallup Analytics. Income data from the World Development Indicators Database, Life expectancy data from the United Nations, Rule of Law data from the Worldwide Governance Indicators.

  2. Notes: The dependent variable is the efficiency score for each country and year. Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered at the country level. Models (5)–(8) exclude low-income countries. FE = fixed effects.

  3. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.

5.2 Second Stage: Country Fixed-effects Regressions

In Table 4, we explore the factors that improve or hinder the efficiency with which countries in our sample translate endowments into subjective well-being. This analysis is especially policy-relevant as it helps identify what kind of interventions can help countries improve or maintain their relative subjective well-being scores.

All regressions include time and country fixed effects, which mitigate the influence of shocks, such as the recent economic crisis, and time-invariant country-specific factors, such as culture or norms. Models (1)–(4) use the sample of 91 nations, while models (5)–(8) exclude the low-income countries listed in Table A2. Models (1) and (5) incorporate controls for social support, generosity, the rule of law and freedom, Models (2) and (6) add all employment status variables, while the rest of the models vary in terms of the included employment status controls. Each country’s efficiency score and not absolute life evaluation levels is the dependent variable in these regressions. We transformed the efficiency score, so that positive coefficient estimates indicate efficiency improvements while negative ones designate efficiency reductions.

The results demonstrate that freedom perceptions and a better institutional environment – as proxied by the rule of law – improve efficiency. While the coefficient estimate for freedom is statistically insignificant in Models (5)–(8), its positive sign indicates that countries in which citizens have the freedom to choose the kinds of lives that they value are also more efficient in translating income, health, and education into subjective well-being. This finding resonates with the capability approach’s insights and its emphasis on capabilities and freedoms to achieve well-being. Indeed, freedom of choice and the opportunities for people to pursue the kind of lives they have reasons to value seems to be a key factor determining how they use the resources that they have at their disposal.

Moreover, the rule of law variable is statistically significant throughout the specifications, implying that countries with well-functioning institutions that guarantee freedoms are relatively more happiness-efficient. This finding parallels the finding that institutions are also determinants of absolute subjective well-being levels (Bjørnskov et al. 2010; Frey and Stutzer 2000; Frey and Stutzer 2002; Helliwell and Huang 2008; Nikolova 2016; Otrachshenko et al. 2016; Rode 2013). Functioning institutions and the rules of the game they impose can enable individuals to invest in their health or human capital or increase their incomes by safeguarding their investments, making it possible to achieve relatively high levels of subjective well-being. Formal institutions also shape the quality of society’s social fabric and functioning (Berggren and Bjørnskov 2020), which means that people can feel free and safe to take full advantage of the resources they have. From a policy perspective, these results imply that improving the quality of formal institutions will improve both relative and absolute subjective well-being.

In addition, social support, which is a measure of the quality of social interactions and informal institutions’ functioning, also improves efficiency. However, its coefficient estimate is only marginally statistically significant. This result is above and beyond the cultural norms captured in the country fixed-effects and formal institutions, which are measured using the rule of law. As such, this result implies that informal interactions and the overall social capital in society can be decisive in reducing inefficiencies. Fostering trust and relatedness in society not only has direct benefits in terms of improving absolute well-being but also in terms of reducing and eliminating subjective well-being inefficiencies.

Next, we discuss the employment status controls, which reflect labor market conditions. In Models (4) and (8), employment status variables associated with choice and flexibility, such as voluntary part-time employment and self-employment, attract positive, albeit marginally or non-statistically significant coefficient estimates, suggesting that they enhance well-being efficiency. By contrast, unemployment unequivocally reduces efficiency (Models (3) and (7)). This finding resonates with the results in Binder and Broekel (2012a). It suggests that unemployment is not only detrimental to absolute life evaluation levels but also to the efficiency with which subjective well-being levels are achieved.

Online Appendix B also features a battery of additional analyses as well as a commentary accompanying these results. Specifically, we offer heterogeneity analyses by World Bank country income classification. We also perform several sensitivity checks: we replace the rule of law with generalized trust, we change the value of α and rely on the order-m technique; we rely on financial satisfaction rather than life evaluations, as the output variable; we change the measurement of the input variables, show results only using GDP per capita as an input, and document the findings without the imputations necessary to achieve a fully balanced sample. All these alternative specifications provide unequivocal support for the robustness of our findings.

For completeness, the estimations of the determinants of efficiency scores without country fixed effects are available in Table C1 in Online Appendix C. As such, these specifications do not hold constant time-invariant heterogeneity at the country level. The most notable distinction with the baseline results showcased in Table 4 is that the rule of law variable now attracts a negative and statistically significant coefficient estimate. The coefficient estimate for freedom is positive and statistically significant when we do not control for country fixed effects in Table C1. However, it is statistically insignificant in the main results, suggesting that it is driven by country-level factors that do not change over time.

All in all, the second-stage analyses reveal several important findings, which have direct policy implications. Specifically, fostering social cohesion, freedom, and formal institutions will likely improve relative subjective well-being and help societies reach the same, or even higher, levels of flourishing and well-being without relying on continuous economic growth.

6 Limitations, Discussion, and Conclusion

The approach used in this paper helps identify inefficiencies in how countries achieve subjective well-being, given a set of resources. We acknowledge that the happiness efficiency approach cannot deal with the reverse causality between life evaluations and determinants, such as health, education, and income. While health affects life satisfaction, for example, those who are more satisfied with their health also have better health outcomes. As such, the insights generated by the first stage analyses are purely descriptive. Also, health may make the conversion of other factors into happiness more efficient, a point also made by Binder and Broekel (2012a). More substantively, the approach offers no guidance into what factors are resources as opposed to background characteristics. Indeed, a similar problem exists in the capability approach, whereby functionings, resources, and conversion factors are highly interdependent, which Binder and Coad (2011) call “the circularity problem.” Dealing with these interdependencies, both conceptually and econometrically, while challenging, should be prioritized in future research.

These limitations notwithstanding, we substantively contribute to the novel science of well-being measurement by estimating the happiness efficiency scores for a balanced panel of 91 countries at different development levels. In addition, we demonstrate which factors and background characteristics enhance or reduce efficiency, which has direct implications for policy and society. Importantly, from a development economics perspective, we demonstrate that large improvements in subjective well-being efficiency are possible worldwide. Such improvements could be achieved by enhancing formal institutions, such as the rule of law, or increasing freedom of choice. Social networks – which are often stronger in poorer countries – also reduce inefficiencies, as we show in the second-stage results in Online Appendix B.

As such, our results have direct implications for informing discussions about sustainable development, which are becoming increasingly important in light of international agreements and frameworks, such as the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) and the Paris Agreement. The idea that current levels of subjective well-being can be sustained and even increased without generating further economic growth is also appealing from an ecological economics viewpoint.

Our analyses are useful to policymakers in countries with low and high relative subjective well-being. First, this research reveals inefficiencies and also the factors that can help reduce these. Second, relatively efficient countries can use the approach proposed in this paper to monitor their performance over time as relative rankings change. In addition, such countries can also apply relative subjective well-being analysis to explore differences between rural and urban areas better.

Furthermore, our results can shed light on one particular challenge in happiness economics, namely hedonic adaptation. Research shows that individuals adapt – albeit imperfectly – to most positive and negative life shocks and events, such as divorce, the death of a spouse, marriage, rising income, or the birth of a child. Complete adaptation implies that life events initially lower or increase subjective well-being, whereas, after some time, subjective well-being levels return to their original levels. If subjective well-being levels always return to a genetically predetermined set point, policy interventions aiming to improve efficiency may be ineffective. While earlier work suggested that the genetic component of subjective well-being could be as high as 52% (Lykken and Tellegen 1996), more recent studies suggest that it is at most 33% (De Neve et al. 2012). Regardless of the exact share of the genetic component of SWB, complete adaptation would imply that efficiency-enhancing interventions would only lead to temporary rather than long-lasting improvements in subjective well-being. Nevertheless, arguably, even non-permanent increases in subjective well-being can be socially-optimal, given that a large literature shows that even temporary improvements in SWB lead to higher productivity, for example (Oswald, Proto, and Sgroi 2015). Moreover, even in the presence of adaptation, researchers can learn under what conditions temporary improvements in SWB can become long-lasting (Diener, Lucas, and Schollon 2006). However, a large body of recent economic research shows that adaptation to income and other aspects of economic and social life is incomplete. For instance, people do not fully adapt to illnesses and do not adapt at all to unemployment, pollution, and the loss of their own business (Clark 2016; Nikolova and Ayhan 2019; Nikolova, Nikolaev, and Popova 2020). Yet, even if there is a complete hedonic adaptation, efficiency analyses can help shed light on reaching given levels of SWB with the least possible levels of resources, which underscores the approach’s usefulness.[9]

Well-being efficiency analyses can thus yield important policy-relevant information when it comes to collective adaptation. Specifically, at the country level, collective adaptation implies that nations can report high subjective well-being levels despite poor institutions or circumstances because they adjust to what is considered possible or tolerable. For example, Latin Americans are happy with their daily lives despite high crime and corruption (Graham 2011). Collectively, adaptation is sub-optimal as it promotes the persistence of bad equilibria, such as poor healthcare systems and public goods and undemocratic institutions, which may result in the erroneous policy conclusion that improving absolute subjective well-being scores requires no policy intervention. Happiness efficiency scores can help to shed light on identifying such bad equilibria. Consider, for example, a country with a poor institutional environment but high absolute levels of subjective well-being due to adaptation. As a first step, efficiency analyses will reveal that this country is achieving its (high) subjective well-being levels inefficiently relative to other countries. As a second step, analyzing which factors help explain efficiency differentials across countries can reveal that improving institutional or other characteristics can yield efficiency gains. The country can achieve higher well-being levels if institutions, to which people have adapted, are improved. Although a country’s absolute subjective well-being score may be high due to adaptation to bad circumstances, relative happiness, as reflected by the efficiency score, will suggest that absolute happiness levels could be higher. Nonetheless, whether improving long-term subjective well-being through enhancing efficiency is possible and what the appropriate instruments to do so remain an open question.

In a world where there is growing pressure on governments to look beyond the traditional way of formulating policies, research on relative subjective well-being in general, and our study in particular, can encourage considering policies that will not only increase endowments but also using existing endowments more efficiently to increase the quality of life of their citizens. Given the growing importance of subjective well-being measures in economics and public policy, there has been a growing urgency in understanding what determines subjective well-being but also how to use measures, such as life satisfaction and happiness in policy decisions. Thus, our research poses an important question about whether the same policy instruments that raise absolute life evaluation levels or happiness are relevant in improving the efficiency with which flourishing and well-being are achieved, which future research should prioritize.


Corresponding author: Milena Nikolova, University of Groningen, Faculty of Economics and Business, Global Economics & Management, Nettelbosje 2, 9747 AE¸ Groningen, The Netherlands; Institute of Labor Economics (IZA), Schaumburg-Lippe-Str. 5-9, 53113, Bonn, Germany; and The Brookings Institution, Washington, DC, 20036, USA, E-mail:

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank the Editor, Frans de Vries, and two anonymous referees for the thorough and thoughtful comments and feedback. We are also indebted to Carol Graham and Martin Binder for helpful comments and encouragement. In addition, we are grateful to IZA Brown Bag and SITE Research Seminar participants for constructive critiques. We thank Sarah Stahlmann and Daria Golokhvastova for research assistance, Margard Ody for locating literature, and Georgios Tassoukis of IZA and Jessica Chi Ying of WHO for data help and suggestions. Finally, we acknowledge copy-editing support from Richard Forsythe. The authors are also grateful to the data services of the IDSC of IZA and the Gallup Organization for access to Gallup Analytics. All errors are ours. The paper was drafted while Nikolova was a Research Associate at IZA and revised at the University of Groningen. The first version of this paper appeared as IZA DP No. 10744 in May 2017 and should be replaced with the current version, which is substantively new.

References

Adsera, A., C. Boix, and M. Payne. 2003. “Are you Being Served? Political Accountability and Quality of Government.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 19 (2): 445–90, https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewg017.Search in Google Scholar

Anand, S., and A. Sen. 2000. “The Income Component of the Human Development Index.” Journal of Human Development 1 (1): 83–106, https://doi.org/10.1080/14649880050008782.Search in Google Scholar

Aragon, Y., A. Daouia, and C. Thomas-Agnan. 2005. “Nonparametric Frontier Estimation: A Conditional Quantile-Based Approach.” Econometric Theory 21 (2): 358–89, https://doi.org/10.1017/s0266466605050206.Search in Google Scholar

Berggren, N., and C. Bjørnskov. 2020. “Institutions and Life Satisfaction.” In Handbook of Labor, Human Resources and Population Economics, edited by K. Zimmermann. Cham: Springer International Publishing.10.1007/978-3-319-57365-6_192-1Search in Google Scholar

Binder, M., and T. Broekel. 2011. “Applying a Nonparametric Efficiency Analysis to Measure Conversion Efficiency in Great Britain.” Journal of Human Development and Capabilities 12 (2): 257–81, https://doi.org/10.1080/19452829.2011.571088.Search in Google Scholar

Binder, M., and T. Broekel. 2012a. “Happiness No Matter the Cost? an Examination on How Efficiently Individuals Reach Their Happiness Levels.” Journal of Happiness Studies 13 (4): 621–45, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10902-011-9283-5.Search in Google Scholar

Binder, M., and T. Broekel. 2012b. “The Neglected Dimension of Well-Being: Analyzing the Development of ‘Conversion Efficiency’ in Great Britain.” The Journal of Socio-Economics 41 (1): 37–47, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2011.10.002.Search in Google Scholar

Binder, M., and A. Coad. 2011. “Disentangling the Circularity in Sen’s Capability Approach: An Analysis of the Co-evolution of Functioning Achievement and Resources.” Social Indicators Research 103 (3): 327–55, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-010-9714-4.Search in Google Scholar

Bjørnskov, C., A. Dreher, and J. A. Fischer. 2010. “Formal Institutions and Subjective Well-Being: Revisiting the Cross-Country Evidence.” European Journal of Political Economy 26 (4): 419–30, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2010.03.001.Search in Google Scholar

Cantril, H. 1965. Pattern of Human Concerns. New Brunswick, New Jersey: Rutgers University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Cazals, C., J. P. Florens, and L. Simar. 2002. “Nonparametric Frontier Estimation: A Robust Approach.” Journal of Econometrics 106 (1): 1–25, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0304-4076(01)00080-x.Search in Google Scholar

Clark, A. E. 2016. “Adaptation and the Easterlin Paradox.” In Advances in Happiness Research, edited by T. Tachibanaki, 75–94: Springer.10.1007/978-4-431-55753-1_6Search in Google Scholar

Cordero, J. M., C. Polo, D. Santín, and G. Sicilia. 2016. “Monte‐Carlo Comparison of Conditional Nonparametric Methods and Traditional Approaches to Include Exogenous Variables.” Pacific Economic Review 21 (4): 483–97, https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0106.12194.Search in Google Scholar

Cordero, J. M., J. Salinas-Jiménez, and M. M. Salinas-Jiménez. 2017. “Exploring Factors Affecting the Level of Happiness across Countries: A Conditional Robust Nonparametric Frontier Analysis.” European Journal of Operational Research 256 (2): 663–72, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2016.07.025.Search in Google Scholar

Daouia, A. I., and L. Simar. 2005. “Robust Nonparametric Estimators of Monotone Boundaries.” Journal of Multivariate Analysis 96 (2): 311–31, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmva.2004.10.005.Search in Google Scholar

Daouia, A., and L. Simar. 2007. “Nonparametric Efficiency Analysis: A Multivariate Conditional Quantile Approach.” Journal of Econometrics 140 (2): 375–400, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2006.07.002.Search in Google Scholar

Daraio, C., and L. Simar. 2005. “Introducing Environmental Variables in Nonparametric Frontier Models: A Probabilistic Approach.” Journal of Productivity Analysis 24 (1): 93–121, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-005-3042-8.Search in Google Scholar

Daraio, C., and L. Simar. 2007. Advanced Robust and Nonparametric Methods in Efficiency Analysis: Methodology and Applications: Springer Science & Business Media.Search in Google Scholar

De Neve, J. E., N. A. Christakis, J. H. Fowler, and B. S. Frey. 2012. “Genes, Economics, and Happiness.” Journal of Neuroscience, Psychology, and Economics 5 (4), https://doi.org/10.1037/a0030292.Search in Google Scholar

Debnath, R. M., and R. Shankar. 2014. “Does Good Governance Enhance Happiness: A Cross Nation Study.” Social Indicators Research 116 (1): 235–53, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-013-0275-1.Search in Google Scholar

Diener, E., R. E. Lucas, and C. N. Scollon. 2006. “Beyond the Hedonic Treadmill: Revising the Adaptation Theory of Well-Being.” American Psychologist 61: 305–14, https://doi.org/10.1037/0003-066x.61.4.305.Search in Google Scholar

Dyson, R. G., R. Allen, A. S. Camanho, V. V. Podinovski, C. S. Sarrico, and E. A. Shale. 2001. “Pitfalls and Protocols in DEA.” European Journal of Operational Research 132 (2): 245–59, https://doi.org/10.1016/s0377-2217(00)00149-1.Search in Google Scholar

Easterlin, R. A. 2017. “Paradox Lost?.” Review of Behavioral Economics 4 (4): 311–39, https://doi.org/10.1561/105.00000068.Search in Google Scholar

Exton, C., C. Smith, and D. Vandendriessche. 2015. Comparing Happiness across the World. OECD Statistics Directorate Working. Paper No. 62.Search in Google Scholar

Frey, B. S., and A. Stutzer. 2000. “Happiness, Economy and Institutions.” The Economic Journal 110 (466): 918–38, https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0297.00570.Search in Google Scholar

Frey, B. S., and A. Stutzer. 2002. “What Can Economists Learn from Happiness Research?.” Journal of Economic Literature 40 (2): 402–35, https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.40.2.402.Search in Google Scholar

Gallup Inc. 2015. Gallup Analytics (2009 – 2014).Search in Google Scholar

Graham, C. 2011. “Adaptation amidst Prosperity and Adversity: Insights from Happiness Studies from Around the World.” The World Bank Research Observer 26 (1): 105–37, https://doi.org/10.1093/wbro/lkq004.Search in Google Scholar

Graham, C. 2016. “Amitai Etzioni’s Critique of Happiness.” Society 53 (3): 287–88, https://doi.org/10.1007/s12115-016-0013-9.Search in Google Scholar

Graham, C., and M. Nikolova. 2015. “Bentham or Aristotle in the Development Process? an Empirical Investigation of Capabilities and Subjective Well-Being.” World Development 68: 163–79, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2014.11.018.Search in Google Scholar

Graham, C., K. Laffan, and S. Pinto. 2018. “Well-being in Metrics and Policy.” Science 362 (6412): 287–88, https://doi.org/10.1126/science.aau5234.Search in Google Scholar

Helliwell, J. F., and H. Huang. 2008. “How’s Your Government? International Evidence Linking Good Government and Well-Being.” British Journal of Political Science 38 (4): 595–619, https://doi.org/10.1017/s0007123408000306.Search in Google Scholar

Helliwell, J. F., H. Huang, and S. Wang. 2016. “The Distribution of World Happiness.” In World Happiness Report 2016, edited by J. F. Helliwell, R. Layard, and J. Sachs, 8–48. New York:.Search in Google Scholar

Hick, R. 2016. “Between Income and Material Deprivation in the UK: In Search of Conversion Factors.” Journal of Human Development and Capabilities 17 (1): 35–54, https://doi.org/10.1080/19452829.2015.1076772.Search in Google Scholar

Hickel, J. 2020. “The Sustainable Development Index: Measuring the Ecological Efficiency of Human Development in the Anthropocene.” Ecological Economics 167: 106331, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2019.05.011.Search in Google Scholar

Kaufmann, D., A. Kraay, and M. Mastruzzi. 2010. The Worldwide Governance Indicators: Methodology and Analytical Issues. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 5430. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1682130.10.1596/1813-9450-5430Search in Google Scholar

Lykken, D., and A. Tellegen. 1996. “Happiness Is a Stochastic Phenomenon.” Psychology Science 7 (3): 186–89, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9280.1996.tb00355.x.Search in Google Scholar

MacKerron, G. 2012. “Happiness Economics from 35 000 Feet.” Journal of Economic Surveys 26 (4): 705–35, https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6419.2010.00672.x.Search in Google Scholar

Martinetti, E. C. 2000. “A Multidimensional Assessment of Well-Being Based on Sen’s Functioning Approach.” Rivista Internazionale di Scienze Sociali 108 (2): 207–39.Search in Google Scholar

Møller, V. 2001. “Happiness Trends under Democracy: Where Will the New South African.” Journal of Happiness Studies 2: 33–53.10.1023/A:1011557404822Search in Google Scholar

Møller, V. 2004. “Quality of Life in a Divided Society.” In Challenges for Quality of Life in the Contemporary World, Social Indicators Research Series, Vol. 24, edited by W. Glatzer, S. Von Below, and M. Stoffregen, 297–310. Dordrecht: Springer, https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1011557404822.10.1007/978-1-4020-2903-5_18Search in Google Scholar

Nikolova, M. 2016. “Minding the Happiness Gap: Political Institutions and Perceived Quality of Life in Transition.” European Journal of Political Economy 45: 129–48, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2016.07.008.Search in Google Scholar

Nikolova, M. 2019. “Happiness: Using Subjective Well-Being Metrics to Gauge Development.” In Routledge Handbook of Development Ethics, edited by J. Drydyk, and L. Keleher, 84–92. New York, NY: Routledge.10.4324/9781315626796-10Search in Google Scholar

Nikolova, M., and S. H. Ayhan. 2019. “Your Spouse Is Fired! How Much Do You Care?.” Journal of Population Economics 32 (3): 799–844, https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-018-0693-0.Search in Google Scholar

Nikolova, M., B. Nikolaev, and O. Popova. 2020. “The Perceived Well-Being and Health Costs of Exiting Self-Employment.” Small Business Economics. in press, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-020-00374-4.Search in Google Scholar

OECD. 2013. OECD Guidelines on Measuring Subjective Well-Being. Paris: Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development, OECD Publishing.Search in Google Scholar

Oswald, A. J., E. Proto, and D. Sgroi. 2015. “Happiness and Productivity.” Journal of Labor Economics 33 (4): 789–822, https://doi.org/10.1086/681096.Search in Google Scholar

Otrachshenko, V., O. Popova, and J. Tavares. 2016. “Psychological Costs of Currency Transition: Evidence from the Euro Adoption.” European Journal of Political Economy 45: 89–100, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2016.10.002.Search in Google Scholar

Patrick, R., A. Shaw, A. Freeman, C. Henderson-Wilson, J. Lawson, M. Davison, and C. K. F. Lee. 2019. “Human Wellbeing and the Health of the Environment: Local Indicators that Balance the Scales.” Social Indicators Research 146 (3): 651–67, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-019-02140-w.Search in Google Scholar

Pillarisetti, R. J., and J. C. J. M. van den Bergh. 2013. “Aggregate Indices for Identifying Environmentally Responsible Nations: An Empirical Analysis and Comparison.” International Journal of Environmental Studies 70 (1): 140–50, https://doi.org/10.1080/00207233.2012.752059.Search in Google Scholar

Ravallion, M. 2005. “On Measuring Aggregate ‘Social Efficiency’.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 53 (2): 273–92, https://doi.org/10.1086/425380.Search in Google Scholar

Rode, M. 2013. “Do Good Institutions Make Citizens Happy, or Do Happy Citizens Build Better Institutions?.” Journal of Happiness Studies 14 (5): 1479–505, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10902-012-9391-x.Search in Google Scholar

Sen, A. 1999. Development as Freedom. New York, NY: Anchor Books.Search in Google Scholar

Simar, L., and P. W. Wilson. 2008. Statistical Inference in Nonparametric Frontier Models: Recent Developments and Perspectives. The Measurement of Productive Efficiency, edited by H. Fried, C. A. K. Lovell, and S. S. Schmidt, 421–521: Oxford University Press, Inc.10.1093/acprof:oso/9780195183528.003.0004Search in Google Scholar

Stone, A. A, and C. Mackie. 2014. Subjective Well-Being: Measuring Happiness, Suffering, and Other Dimensions of Experience: National Academies Press.Search in Google Scholar

Tauchmann, H. 2012. “Partial Frontier Efficiency Analysis.” Stata Journal 12 (3): 461–78, https://doi.org/10.1177/1536867x1201200309.Search in Google Scholar

United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division. 2015. World Population Prospects: The 2015 Revision, DVD Edition.Search in Google Scholar


Supplementary Material

The online version of this article offers supplementary material (https://doi.org/10.1515/bejeap-2019-0396).


Received: 2019-11-17
Accepted: 2020-07-06
Published Online: 2020-08-25

© 2020 Milena Nikolova and Olga Popova, published by De Gruyter, Berlin/Boston

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.

Downloaded on 25.4.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejeap-2019-0396/html
Scroll to top button